Abstract
Was the constitutional movement in Iran a massive tax revolt? If so, would this challenge its image as the harbinger of a new democratic era as judged by the appearance of globally familiar features like a representative assembly, written constitution, voting, political parties, and a modern public sphere with Enlightenment-inspired quest for freedom and rights entrenched in the law? An entirely new picture emerges when the constitutional movement is approached through the lens of petitions. Regardless of location, petitions of this period show astonishing uniformity about the public wants, reveal why the public was in a perpetual state of revolt throughout Iran, or why it had set its hopes on the Assembly in Tehran. The onerous local taxes (tafavut-i `amal) appear here as the main source of public dissatisfaction, as well as the administrators who enforced them, starting from the governor to the tax procurator (pishkar), the overseers (mubashir or mustufi), down to the collectors. Surprisingly though, if the public refused the local taxes, it considered the central ones as entirely legitimate and remitted them upon demand. Through petitioning the Assembly that functioned as a sympathetic intermediary, the public obliged the central and local governments to enter unprecedented negotiations that resulted in small and large victories like dismissal of high officials, and moderated taxes. Also transformed was the culture of politics that now began to speak in the language of rights. The associations (anjuman) played key roles in mobilizing the public. With the monarchy’s defeat and ascendance of the Assembly in the second constitutional period, petitions changed again. Provinces with powerful associations like Azerbaijan, Gilan, Khorasan, and perhaps others, now laid claim to the central taxes and demanded expenditure of the entire tax receipts in the locality. Their new demand, beyond creating a rift with the Assembly and the central government, prepared the ground for the emergence of the later decentralist movements such as Jangal, Khiyabani, and others, which showed tremendous continuity with the rhetoric and membership of the local associations of this period. By shifting the focus to actors from the ground up, this study suggests that bargaining over taxes was the dominant democratizing thrust of this movement. With collective petitioning and information flow through the associations and their independent presses, this period also witnessed the emergence of an alternative public sphere.
Discipline
Geographic Area
Sub Area
None